Malthusian assumptions, Boserupian response in models of the transitions to agriculture

نویسنده

  • Carsten Lemmen
چکیده

In the many transitions from foraging to agropastoralism it is debated whether the primary drivers are innovations in technology or increases of population. The driver discussion traditionally separates Malthusian (technology driven) from Boserupian (population driven) theories. I present a numerical model of the transitions to agriculture and discuss this model in the light of the population versus technology debate and in Boserup’s analytical framework in development theory. Although my model is based on ecological—Neomalthusian— principles, the coevolutionary positive feedback relationship between technology and population results in a seemingly Boserupian response: innovation is greatest when population pressure is highest. This outcome is not only visible in the theory-driven reduced model, but is also present in a corresponding “real world” simulator which was tested against archaeological data, demonstrating the relevance and validity of the coevolutionary model. The lesson to be learned is that not all that acts Boserupian needs Boserup at its core. 1 Transitions to agriculture The relationship between humans and their environment underwent a radical change during the last 10,000 years: from mobile and small groups of foraging people to sedentary extensive cultivators and on to high-density intensive agriculture modern society; these transitions fundamentally turned the formerly predominantly passive human user of the environment into an active component of the Earth system. The most striking global impact is only visible and measurable during the last 150 years (Crutzen and Stoermer, 2000; Crutzen, 2002); much earlier, however, the use of forest resources for metal smelting from early Roman times and the medieval extensive agricultural system had already changed the landscape (Barker, 2011; Kaplan et al., 2009); global climate effects of these early extensive cultivation and harvesting practices are yet under debate (Ruddiman, 2003; Lemmen, 2010; Kaplan et al., 2011; Stocker et al., 2011). ∗To appear in: “Society, Nature and History: The Legacy of Ester Boserup”, Springer, Vienna 1 ar X iv :1 10 8. 25 85 v2 [ qbi o. PE ] 2 4 M ay 2 01 2 Transitions to agriculture occurred in almost every region of the world, earliest in China and the Near East over 9000 years ago (Kuijt and Goring-morris, 2002; Londo et al., 2006), and latest in Australia and Oceania with the arrival of Polynesian and European immigrants few hundred years ago (Diamond and Bellwood, 2003). While each local transition can be considered revolutionary, the many diverse mechanisms, environments, and cultural contexts of each agricultural transition make it difficult to speak of the one ’Neolithic revolution’, as the transition to farming and herding was termed by V. G. Childe almost a century ago (Childe, 1925). The transitions from foraging to farming were not only one big step, but may have consisted of intermediary stages: Bogaard (2005) looks at the transition in terms of the land use system: she sees first inadvertent cultivation then horticulture then simple and then advanced agriculture, while Boserup (1965) discriminates these stages by the management practice ranging from forest, bush and short fallow to annual and multi cropping. In contemporary hunting-gathering societies much less time has to be devoted to procuring food from hunting and gathering opposed to agriculture and herding (e.g., Sahlins, 1972); less labor is required for long fallow systems compared to intensive multi-cropping agriculture(Boserup, 1965). So why farm? Different responses from archaeology (Barker, 2011), demography (Turchin and Nefedov, 2009), historical economy (Weisdorf , 2005), and ecosystem modeling (Wirtz and Lemmen, 2003) call upon processes such as social reorganization, the value of leisure, changing resources, or coevolutionary thresholds. The probably simplest relationship was proposed by Malthus (1798, p.11), namely that more production sustains larger population. With larger population, more production is possible, thereby constituting a positive feedback loop, which ideally results in ever greater (geometric) growth and productivity. That this is not the case in a world with finite resources was expressed by Malthus (1798, p. 4) by stating that “Population, when unchecked, increases at a geometrical ratio. Subsistence increases only in an arithmetical ratio. A slight acquaintance with numbers will show the immensity of the first power in comparison with the second”. Malthus identified the need for positive and preventive checks to balance population increase with the limited capacity of resources. How does an increase in productivity come about? First and foremost, the input of more labor increases productivity (Malthus, 1798, p. 11), subject to the constraints of finite resources and diminishing returns. Where Malthus, however, focused on extensive productivity increase, the intensification component of productivity increase was highlighted by Boserup (1965). Investments in a more intensive production system would, however, require large additional labor, and the benefits of such investments were often small. To stimulate an investment in more intensive agriculture, Boserup requires population pressure. Both Malthus (1798, 1826) and Boserup (1965, 1981) concentrate on the role of labor (and later division of labor and social/family organization) and innovations which increase area productivity (like storage or tools, requiring relatively more labor for harvesting, building, and tool processing). Both authors neglect the role of labor-independent innovation, or innovations which increase both area and labor productivity; these are innovations in the resources themselves, such as cultivation of higher-yielding grains or imported high yield varieties, or their management such as water rights; this distinction may not be unambiguous for all innovations, it is used here conceptually. Labor-independent innovation can be stimulated by diversity and density of a population, both of which are positively related to population size.

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

منابع مشابه

Malthusian assumptions lead to Boserupian phenology in a global model of the transitions to agriculture

In the many transitions from foraging to agropastoralism it is debated whether innovation in technology or increase of population is the primary driver. The driver discussion traditionally separates Malthusian (technology driven) from Boserupian (population driven) theories. I present a numerical model of the transition to agriculture and discuss this model in the light of the population versus...

متن کامل

Induced intensification: agricultural change in Bangladesh with implications for Malthus and Boserup.

Bangladesh is dominated by a small-holder agrarian economy under extreme stress. Production shortfalls, increasing economic polarization, and chronic malnutrition are persistent, but major famine has been diverted in part by significant growth in agriculture. This recent history is open to both Malthusian and Boserupian interpretations-a history we explore here through a test of the induced int...

متن کامل

Malthusian dynamics in a diverging Europe: Northern Italy, 1650-1881.

Recent empirical research questions the validity of using Malthusian theory in preindustrial England. Using real wage and vital rate data for the years 1650-1881, I provide empirical estimates for a different region: Northern Italy. The empirical methodology is theoretically underpinned by a simple Malthusian model, in which population, real wages, and vital rates are determined endogenously. M...

متن کامل

The Rise of Neolithic Agriculture

The article analyzes the economic reasons behind the rise of Neolithic agriculture some 10,000 years ago in consideration of evidence that agriculture was not associated with increasing standards of living. On the basis of archeological and anthropological literature, the article presents a modelling framework that allows for four broad explanations to the agricultural transition; (i) environme...

متن کامل

Innovation in the Agro-Food Sector: from Technical Innovation-Centred Approaches to Sustainability Transition Processes

Innovation is a complex phenomenon and process involving translation of knowledge into new techniques, products, services. It is considered crucial for sustainable agriculture development and achievement of long-term food security. The review describes the diversity of innovation and relates it to agro-food sector. It also sheds light on different innovation models and explores their contributi...

متن کامل

ذخیره در منابع من


  با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

عنوان ژورنال:

دوره   شماره 

صفحات  -

تاریخ انتشار 2011